The Collaborative Arena

From Zero-Sum to Positive-Sum Engagement
Created By: Harald Blikø, Digitalisation Specialist - CMTr.io
With support from Google Gemini 2.5 Preview Deep Reseach
INTRODUCTION
Beyond Power Politics:
A New Frontier in Stakeholder Engagement
In the complex, high-stakes world of modern project management, the language used to describe stakeholder engagement often borrows from the lexicon of conflict and statecraft. Stakeholders are analysed through the lens of "power" and "interest," alliances are forged, and influence is wielded in a manner reminiscent of "Great Power politics." This framing, while familiar, carries a dangerous and often self-fulfilling prophecy: that stakeholder interactions are fundamentally adversarial, a contest of wills where resources are finite and one party's victory necessitates another's defeat. It presupposes a world of fixed pies and zero-sum outcomes.

This volume of the anthology challenges that foundational assumption. It argues that in today's interconnected project ecosystems, the most advanced form of stakeholder management is not about winning conflicts but about architecting collaboration. The central thesis is that the majority of stakeholder situations are not immutable, fixed-pie contests. Instead, they are dynamic strategic environments that can be consciously redesigned. The experienced project manager can move beyond the role of a mere player reacting to the game and ascend to the role of a game architect, proactively shaping the rules and incentives to foster cooperation. This shift in perspective transforms stakeholder management from a defensive exercise in conflict mitigation to a proactive strategy for collective value creation.

To navigate this new frontier, this report will employ two powerful analytical lenses. The first is Game Theory, the science of strategy, which provides the rigorous models and language needed to analyse interactions between rational stakeholders, predict their behaviours, and understand the deep-seated dynamics of conflict and cooperation.1 It allows us to deconstruct why well-intentioned parties often fall into cycles of distrust and competition, and more importantly, how to create the conditions for sustained collaboration.

The second lens is Value Co-creation, which represents the ultimate objective of this sophisticated approach. Value co-creation moves beyond the transactional delivery of a project for stakeholders to the transformative process of generating new, shared value with them.3 It is the active process of integrating resources and competencies, built on a foundation of trust and continuous interaction, to create outcomes that would be impossible for any single party to achieve alone.3 This is the essence of a positive-sum game: a collaborative endeavour where the total value generated is greater than the sum of its parts, effectively "growing the pie" for everyone involved.5

This report will guide the experienced project manager on a journey through this new paradigm. Section 1 will deconstruct the zero-sum fallacy that pervades many project interactions and introduce the core concepts of game theory, establishing the positive-sum game as the superior strategic objective. Section 2 will explore the classic Prisoner's Dilemma, using it as a microcosm to understand the mechanics of trust, defection, and the strategies required to foster cooperation in iterated interactions. Section 3 will elevate the project manager to the role of "Game Architect," providing a detailed framework for designing collaborative environments by modifying rules, engineering payoffs, and curating players. Section 4 will introduce Social Network Analysis as a powerful tool for moving beyond static stakeholder maps to identify true influencers and build value-creating coalitions. Section 5 will introduce the concept of Blended Value, a framework for expanding the definition of project success to include social and environmental outcomes, thereby creating more "currencies" for negotiation and enlarging the pie. Finally, Section 6 will present a detailed case study on the creation of industry-wide technology standards, demonstrating how these principles were applied in the real world to achieve a monumental collaborative victory.

The journey concludes with a practical playbook, synthesising these concepts into a coherent model for strategic action. The aim is to equip the advanced project manager not just with tools to win a fight, but with the strategic foresight to avoid the fight altogether by creating a better, more valuable, and more collaborative game for all to play.
CHAPTER I
Reframing the Battlefield:
The Shift from Zero-Sum to Positive-Sum Games
The default mindset in many negotiations and resource conflicts is one of scarcity. The underlying assumption, often unspoken, is that the "pie" is fixed. Any slice gained by one stakeholder must be taken from another. This is the world of the zero-sum game, a situation where the net change in value is zero; for every winner, there is an equal and opposite loser.7 This perspective, while applicable to purely competitive scenarios like a game of chess or a single-winner athletic contest, is a dangerously simplistic and often incorrect lens through which to view the complex, multi-faceted interactions of project management.9

I.I - Deconstructing the Zero-Sum Fallacy

In a project context, the zero-sum fallacy manifests frequently. When a budget overrun occurs, the conversation often devolves into a zero-sum battle over who will absorb the cost: the client or the contractor. When a critical resource is needed by two different departments, it is framed as a contest where one department's gain is the other's loss. A negotiation over project scope is seen as a tug-of-war, where any additional feature for the client is a direct cost increase for the project team. This mindset is insidious because it frames all participants as adversaries from the outset, stifling the potential for creative problem-solving and fostering a culture of suspicion and defensiveness.11 It forces stakeholders to focus on claiming value rather than creating it.

The reality, however, is that most business and project interactions are not zero-sum. Value is not a fixed quantity to be divided; it is a dynamic quality that can be created.7 The modern understanding of economics and strategy has moved beyond the idea that profit can only be booked at the expense of a competitor.7 Instead, it recognises that collaboration can lead to outcomes where all parties are better off. This is the realm of the non-zero-sum game.

To analyse these dynamics with precision, it is necessary to adopt the formal language of game theory. This framework models strategic interactions and provides a structured way to understand and predict the choices of independent, rational actors.2

I.II - Introducing the Game Theory Lexicon

At its core, any strategic interaction within a project can be modeled as a "game." The key components of this game are2:

  • Players: These are the decision-making entities involved in the interaction. In a project, players can be individuals (the project manager, a lead engineer), groups (the development team, the quality assurance department), or entire organisations (the client company, a key supplier, a regulatory body).13
  • Strategies: These are the complete plans of action a player can choose. For any given situation, a player has a set of available strategies. For example, in a negotiation with a supplier over a delay, the project manager's strategies might include 'Impose contractual penalty,' 'Offer a collaborative solution,' or 'Escalate to senior management'.15
  • Payoffs: These are the outcomes or consequences for each player, resulting from the specific combination of strategies chosen by all players. Payoffs can be quantified (e.g., profit, cost savings, days saved on a schedule) or qualified (e.g., enhanced reputation, damaged relationship). The crucial element of game theory is that one player's payoff is contingent on the strategies implemented by all other players.2
Using this lexicon, we can move beyond simplistic labels and analyse the underlying structure of stakeholder interactions.

I.III - The World of Non-Zero-Sum

Non-zero-sum games are those in which the sum of the players' payoffs is not zero. The outcomes are not a simple win-lose dichotomy; it is possible for all participants to win, or for all participants to lose.7 These games are more representative of the real world because they contain both competitive and cooperative elements. Players often have some interests that are complementary and some that are in direct opposition.17

Consider the classic "Battle of the Sexes" game. A couple wishes to spend an evening together (a cooperative interest) but one prefers a boxing match while the other prefers the ballet (a competitive interest). Both would rather attend their less-preferred event together than attend their preferred event alone. The best outcomes occur when they coordinate, but there is conflict over which coordinated outcome is best.17 This mirrors many project situations where stakeholders agree on the overall goal (e.g., a successful project launch) but disagree on the specific path to get there (e.g., which features to prioritise).

Within the non-zero-sum world, two primary dynamics exist:
  • Negative-Sum Dynamics: In these "lose-lose" scenarios, the sum of the payoffs is negative. Unfettered competition, trade wars, or a project where infighting leads to total failure are examples. The selfish actions of all parties lead to a collective outcome that is worse for everyone than if they had found a way to cooperate.5
  • Positive-Sum Dynamics: This is the strategic ideal. In a positive-sum game, collaboration creates new value, making the total "pie" larger than it was at the start.5 The aggregate gains are greater than the aggregate losses. A successful trade agreement that boosts the economies of all participating nations is a classic example.9 In a project, this could be a joint venture where two companies pool their technologies to create a new product that neither could have developed alone, capturing a new market and generating profits for both.7
The perception of a game as zero-sum versus positive-sum is not an objective reality but a strategic choice made by the participants, often implicitly. The most powerful act a project manager can perform is to make this choice explicit and consciously steer stakeholders toward a positive-sum framing. This is achieved by fundamentally reframing the problem. The question is shifted from a distributive one to a creative one. Instead of asking, "How do we divide this limited budget?" the question becomes, "How can we collaboratively redesign the scope to deliver the most critical value within the available funds, potentially unlocking new efficiencies that benefit us all?" This is the difference between arguing over how to slice a cake and collaborating on a recipe for a bigger, better cake that might also include ice cream.5 By presenting data on how cooperation can lead to mutual gains - such as shared risk reduction, new market opportunities, or enhanced long-term relationships - the project manager alters the perceived rules of the game before the first move is even played. This elevates the project manager's role from a simple negotiator to a facilitator of collective value discovery.

The following table provides a practical comparison of how common project challenges are perceived and addressed through these two competing mindsets.
For the experienced project manager, the behaviours in the "Zero-Sum Approach" column are instantly recognisable. By presenting a direct, practical "Positive-Sum Approach" for the same challenges, the abstract concept of reframing the game becomes a concrete and actionable tool, making the paradigm shift tangible and applicable to daily strategic decisions.
CHAPTER II
The Cooperator's Dilemma: Navigating Trust and Rational Self-Interest
Even when stakeholders recognize the potential for a positive-sum outcome, achieving it is not guaranteed. The path to collaboration is fraught with a fundamental tension between collective benefit and individual self-interest. This tension is perfectly encapsulated by one of the most famous models in game theory: the Prisoner's Dilemma. Understanding this dilemma is critical for any project manager, as it provides a powerful microcosm of the trust-based challenges that arise in virtually every project.2

II.I - The Prisoner's Dilemma as a Project Microcosm

The classic Prisoner's Dilemma scenario involves two suspects arrested for a crime, held in separate cells, and unable to communicate. The prosecutor lacks enough evidence for a major conviction unless one or both confess. Each prisoner is offered a deal.

The choices and outcomes are as follows20:
  1. If both prisoners stay silent (Cooperate with each other), they both receive a minor sentence (e.g., 1 year in jail).
  2. If one prisoner confesses (Defects against the other) and the other stays silent (Cooperates), the defector goes free, while the cooperator receives a harsh sentence (e.g., 7 years).
  3. If both prisoners confess (Defect against each other), they both receive a moderate sentence (e.g., 5 years).
The paradox is that while the best collective outcome is for both to cooperate (totalling 2 years of jail time), the most rational individual choice for each prisoner, regardless of what the other does, is to defect.20 From one prisoner's perspective: if the other cooperates, my best move is to defect (go free instead of 1 year). If the other defects, my best move is also to defect (5 years instead of 7). Since both prisoners reason this way, they both defect and end up with a 5-year sentence - a far worse outcome for both than if they had trusted each other and cooperated.

This dynamic plays out constantly in projects. Consider two suppliers working on integrated components of a system. They discover a process innovation. If they both cooperate (share the innovation), the entire project benefits from cost and time savings, and they both receive a moderate bonus. If Supplier A defects (keeps the innovation secret) while Supplier B cooperates (works as normal), Supplier A gains a significant competitive advantage and a larger bonus, while Supplier B looks inefficient. If both defect (hoard their knowledge), the project proceeds inefficiently, and both receive a smaller bonus or even a penalty for the suboptimal outcome.18

II.II - The Nash Equilibrium of Distrust

The tendency to defect in a one-shot Prisoner's Dilemma is explained by the concept of the Nash Equilibrium. A Nash Equilibrium is a state in a game where no player can improve their own payoff by unilaterally changing their strategy, assuming the other players' strategies remain unchanged.2 In the Prisoner's Dilemma, the (Defect, Defect) outcome is a Nash Equilibrium. If both prisoners are confessing, neither one can improve their situation by deciding to stay silent on their own; doing so would result in the harshest sentence.20 This powerful pull toward a mutually destructive equilibrium explains why projects can become mired in cycles of distrust, information hoarding, and self-protective behaviour, even when all stakeholders verbally commit to collaboration.

II.III - The Redeeming Power of Repetition: The Iterated Game

The key to escaping this dilemma lies in recognising that projects are rarely a one-shot game. Stakeholder interactions - from responding to emails to attending weekly meetings to negotiating change orders - constitute an Iterated Prisoner's Dilemma.20 The game is played over and over again. This repetition introduces a crucial new element: the "shadow of the future".1 A stakeholder's actions today create a reputation that will affect the payoffs they receive in all future interactions. The threat of future punishment for defection and the promise of future reward for cooperation fundamentally change the strategic calculation.20

II.IV - Tit-for-Tat: A Strategy for Building Cooperation

In the 1980s, political scientist Robert Axelrod conducted computer tournaments to find the most effective strategy for the Iterated Prisoner's Dilemma. The surprising winner was one of the simplest strategies submitted: Tit-for-Tat, developed by mathematical psychologist Anatol Rapoport.24

The strategy is simple:
  1. Cooperate on the first move.
  2. On every subsequent move, replicate the opponent's previous move.
If the opponent cooperates, you cooperate. If they defect, you defect.24 The success of Tit-for-Tat can be attributed to four key properties:
  • It is Nice: It starts by cooperating, signaling a willingness to trust and never initiating conflict. This immediately opens the door for a mutually beneficial cycle of cooperation.
  • It is Retaliatory (or Provocable): It immediately punishes an opponent's defection. This clarity prevents it from being exploited by aggressive or selfish players. A defector quickly learns that their actions have immediate, negative consequences.
  • It is Forgiving: As soon as an opponent returns to cooperation, Tit-for-Tat immediately reciprocates, also returning to cooperation. It doesn't hold a grudge, which prevents it from getting locked in long, destructive cycles of revenge.
  • It is Clear: The strategy is so simple that the opponent can quickly deduce the pattern. This transparency makes the consequences of their actions predictable, encouraging them to choose cooperation to secure their own best long-term outcome.
For a project manager, using a Tit-for-Tat approach in negotiations and interactions can be a powerful way to build cooperative relationships. It establishes a reputation for being trustworthy and fair, but not a pushover.

II.V - Beyond Simple Reciprocity: The Nuances of Real-World Application

While powerful, a pure Tit-for-Tat strategy has a critical vulnerability in the real world: it is susceptible to signal errors. A single misunderstanding - a misread email, a delayed response misinterpreted as a deliberate slight - can trigger a defection. If both parties are playing strict Tit-for-Tat, this single error can set off an unending "death spiral" of mutual retaliation from which neither can escape.24

To make the strategy more robust for the messy reality of project management, more forgiving variants have been developed:
  • Tit-for-Tat with Forgiveness (or Generous Tit-for-Tat): This strategy involves occasionally cooperating even after an opponent's defection (e.g., cooperating with a 10% probability after being defected against). This small measure of generosity acts as a reset button, giving it the ability to unilaterally break a negative cycle and signal a desire to restore a cooperative relationship.26
  • Tit for Two Tats: This strategy tolerates a single, isolated defection before retaliating. It only defects after the opponent has defected twice in a row. This makes the strategy more resilient to accidental defections or "noise" in communication, preventing an overreaction to a single mistake.24
Tit-for-Tat is not merely a negotiation tactic; it is an algorithm for building and testing trust in low-trust environments. Its true power for a project manager lies in its diagnostic capability. A stakeholder's response to a Tit-for-Tat strategy reveals their underlying disposition - cooperative, exploitative, or simply erratic - far more accurately than their stated intentions. Projects often bring together stakeholders with no prior history, meaning trust is inherently low. The Prisoner's Dilemma demonstrates that in such environments, rational self-interest logically leads to defection. A project manager employing Tit-for-Tat begins with a cooperative move, a small offer of trust, such as sharing a piece of non-critical information early. The stakeholder's response is a clear signal. If they reciprocate, trust is initiated. If they exploit the gesture, they reveal a competitive tendency. The project manager's subsequent moves—rewarding cooperation and retaliating against defection—are not just about that specific interaction but are about teaching the stakeholder the "rules of the game" for this particular project relationship. This establishes a reputation for fairness and predictable reciprocity. Thus, a project manager can use the initial phases of a project, which are a series of small, iterated games, to run this "trust algorithm," gathering invaluable data on which stakeholders are reliable partners versus those who require more structured contractual constraints.

The following payoff matrix visualises this dynamic in a project context, illustrating why the dilemma is so powerful.
This matrix makes the logic starkly clear. The best collective outcome is (+5, +5) from mutual cooperation. However, for Supplier A, regardless of B's choice, defecting yields a better payoff (+10 vs +5 if B cooperates; -5 vs -10 if B defects). The same logic applies to Supplier B. This leads them to the Nash Equilibrium of (-5, -5), a suboptimal outcome for both. The ultimate goal for the project manager is not just to play this game well, but to fundamentally change the game's structure. By fostering trust, establishing clear communication protocols, and creating shared goals and incentive systems, the project manager can alter the payoffs in the matrix, making cooperation the most rational, stable, and rewarding strategy for everyone involved.20
CHAPTER III
The Project Manager as Game Architect:
Designing for Collaboration
The most profound shift in thinking offered by game theory is the evolution of the project manager's role from that of a player to that of an architect. A player reacts to the game as it is presented, attempting to choose the best strategy within a given set of rules and payoffs. An architect, however, understands that the game itself is a designed system. By consciously manipulating the core elements of the game - the rules, the payoffs, and even the players - the project manager can create a strategic environment where the most rational, self-interested choice for every stakeholder is to cooperate and co-create value.13 This is the essence of moving from reactive stakeholder management to proactive strategic design. This section details the three primary levers the project manager can pull to architect a collaborative arena.

III.I - Modifying the Rules of Engagement

The rules of a game define what actions are possible and how interactions occur. In a project, these rules are embodied in its communication protocols and governance structures. Designing these elements is not administrative overhead; it is a strategic act of game design that can either foster or inhibit collaboration.

III.I.I - Communication Protocols: The Infrastructure of Trust

Ambiguity and misinterpretation are prime catalysts for defection in stakeholder relationships. When communication is poor, stakeholders are more likely to assume negative intent, leading to the "death spirals" of mistrust seen in the Prisoner's Dilemma.24 A well-designed communication plan is the antidote. It builds "affordances for trust and communication" directly into the project's operating system.31 An effective plan goes beyond simply listing meetings; it establishes clear, agreed-upon protocols that reduce uncertainty and create a shared understanding32:

  • Defining Channels: The plan must specify which channel is used for which purpose. For example: instant messaging platforms like Slack or Teams for urgent, quick questions; project management tools like Jira for formal task assignments and progress tracking; shared documentation platforms like Confluence for the "single source of truth" on project scope and requirements; and email for formal, official announcements.32 This prevents critical decisions from getting lost in informal chat logs and ensures everyone knows where to find authoritative information.
  • Establishing Frequency and Cadence: A clear schedule for communication—such as daily stand-ups for tactical alignment, weekly progress reports for stakeholders, and monthly steering committee meetings for strategic review—creates a predictable rhythm. This consistency ensures a steady flow of information, prevents surprises, and builds confidence that the project is under control.32
  • Clarifying Audience and Purpose: Every communication act should have a defined audience and purpose. Technical teams require detailed data, while executive stakeholders need concise, high-level summaries.32 By tailoring the message to the audience, the project manager ensures that information is not just sent, but received and understood, enhancing engagement and efficiency.

III.I.II - Governance and Decision-Making: Formalising Collaboration

The project's governance structure sets the formal rules for decision-making. A project manager can architect this structure to compel cooperation. Instead of allowing stakeholders to make decisions in isolated silos, the PM can establish frameworks that require joint problem-solving. Integrated project teams, which co-locate members from the client, contractor, and key supplier organisations, break down "us vs. them" barriers. Joint steering committees, where senior leaders from different stakeholder groups must reach consensus on key decisions, force a shift from adversarial negotiation to collaborative deliberation. These structures change the game by making it impossible to "win" alone; success is defined and achieved collectively.30

III.II - Engineering the Payoffs with Incentive Systems

Perhaps the most direct way to influence stakeholder behaviour is to alter the payoff matrix. Incentive systems are the primary tool for this, aligning individual or group interests with the project's collective goals. A poorly designed system that rewards siloed performance will inevitably produce competitive behaviour, no matter how much collaboration is encouraged verbally. An architected incentive system makes cooperation the most lucrative strategy.

III.II.I - Principles of Effective Incentive Design
Designing an incentive system that genuinely motivates desired behaviour requires careful thought.

Key principles include36:
  • Alignment with Project Goals: Incentives must directly reflect and reward the behaviours that lead to overall project success, not just the success of one department or task.
  • Clarity and Simplicity: Participants must know exactly what is expected of them and believe the goals are achievable. The rules should be simple, transparent, and easy to understand.37
  • Balance: The system should balance short-term incentives (e.g., for meeting a sprint goal) with long-term incentives (e.g., for achieving the final project outcome) to encourage both immediate performance and sustained commitment.36
  • Fairness and Controllability: The rewards must be perceived as fair, and the metrics used must be within the participants' control or significant influence.38
III.II.II - From Individual KPIs to Collective Rewards
The strategic pivot in incentive design is the shift away from rewarding purely individual or functional performance. When a developer is incentivised solely on lines of code written and a QA tester is incentivised solely on bugs found, their incentives are in direct conflict. To engineer cooperation, the payoffs must be shared.

Effective mechanisms include39:
  • Team-Based Bonuses: Rewards are given to the entire project team for achieving collective targets, such as a successful phase gate review or product launch.
  • Gain-Sharing Plans: If the team collaborates to deliver the project under budget or ahead of schedule, a portion of the resulting savings or value is distributed among all contributing team members and stakeholders. This directly ties financial reward to the act of cooperation.
  • Project Milestone Rewards: Celebrating and rewarding the achievement of key project milestones as a group reinforces a sense of shared purpose and collective accomplishment.
III.II.III - The Role of Non-Monetary Incentives
Motivation is not purely financial. For many stakeholders, particularly those in non-profit, academic, or government roles, non-monetary incentives can be equally or even more powerful.38 An effective game architect uses a blend of incentives. A supplier might be motivated by the opportunity to co-author a white paper on an innovative technique used in the project, enhancing their industry reputation. An internal team member might be driven by a public recognition award from a senior executive or the opportunity to receive specialised training. By understanding the unique needs and motivations of each stakeholder, the project manager can tailor a diverse set of payoffs that go beyond the budget line.36

III.III - Curating the Players and the Information

The most advanced level of game architecture involves manipulating the very composition of the game itself—who plays and what they know.

III.III.I - Changing the Players
Sometimes, a game between two entrenched, adversarial stakeholders is stuck in a lose-lose equilibrium. No amount of rule-tweaking or payoff-engineering can break the deadlock. In these cases, the most effective strategy can be to change the players by introducing a new actor into the game.41 Bringing in a respected, neutral third-party mediator can reframe the conversation and introduce new, objective logic. Involving an industry standards body can provide an external benchmark that forces both parties to move from their entrenched positions. This new player alters the network of relationships and introduces new potential strategies, fundamentally changing the game's dynamic.

III.III.II - Managing Information Flow and Asymmetry
Information is power, and information asymmetry - where one player knows something another doesn't - is a key feature of many strategic games.16 A project manager sits at the center of a project's information network and can architect the flow of that information to foster cooperation. By acting as a trusted, central hub, the PM can reduce the uncertainty that often drives defensive, uncooperative behaviour.1 When stakeholders act on incomplete or biased information, they tend to assume the worst and act to protect themselves. By ensuring that all players are working from a common, verified set of facts - a "single source of truth" - the PM removes ambiguity and builds a foundation for rational, collective decision-making.

Ultimately, a project's communication plan and its incentive structure are not separate administrative documents. They are the two primary levers for programming the "source code" of stakeholder behavior. Game theory demonstrates that behaviour is a rational response to the perceived rules and payoffs. The incentive system defines the payoffs, while the communication protocol defines the rules of interaction. An effective project manager designs these elements in concert, creating a single, coherent "choice infrastructure".5 A system that rewards collaboration (the incentive) must be supported by channels that make collaboration easy and safe to perform (the communication protocol). When designed together, they make cooperation the logical, rational, and inevitable path of least resistance for all stakeholders.
CHAPTER IV
Weaving the Web of Influence: Building Value-Creating Coalitions with Network Theory
Traditional stakeholder management tools, such as the ubiquitous power/interest grid, provide a valuable starting point for classifying stakeholders. However, they suffer from a critical limitation: they are static and hierarchical.43 They map stakeholders based on perceived attributes (like formal authority or stated interest) but fail to capture the dynamic, informal, and often hidden web of relationships through which influence actually flows. Work, ideas, and influence do not always follow the neat lines of an organisational chart; they travel through informal social networks.43 To move to a more sophisticated level of engagement, the advanced project manager must learn to see and shape this hidden network. Social Network Analysis (SNA) provides the methodology to do just that, offering a way to visualise and quantify the real structure of stakeholder relationships and identify the true levers of influence.45

IV.I - Identifying the True Influencers with Centrality Measures

SNA moves beyond subjective assessments of power by providing objective, mathematical measures of a stakeholder's importance based on their position within the network. This is known as centrality. A stakeholder in a central position can see more of what is happening in the network and can regulate the flow of information, giving them a high degree of influence regardless of their formal title.47

There are several key types of centrality, each revealing a different kind of influence48:
  • Degree Centrality: This is the most straightforward measure, simply counting the number of direct connections a node (stakeholder) has. Stakeholders with high degree centrality are the network's "hubs." They are highly active and connected, often serving as major conduits for day-to-day information.48
  • Betweenness Centrality: This metric identifies the crucial "brokers" or "gatekeepers." It measures how often a stakeholder lies on the shortest path between two other stakeholders who are not directly connected themselves.43 A stakeholder with high betweenness centrality has significant control over the flow of information and resources between different groups. They can facilitate communication or become a critical bottleneck. These are often the most powerful individuals in the network, as they can connect disparate groups or keep them apart.47
  • Closeness Centrality: This measures how easily a stakeholder can reach all other stakeholders in the network, calculated by the average length of the shortest paths from that node to every other node.48 Stakeholders with high closeness centrality are efficient broadcasters; they can disseminate information throughout the network very quickly.
  • Eigenvector Centrality: This is a more nuanced measure of influence. It posits that a stakeholder's importance comes not just from how many connections they have, but from the importance of the stakeholders they are connected to.49 A stakeholder might have only a few connections, but if those connections are to the most powerful players in the network, their eigenvector centrality will be high. This metric identifies those who have the ear of the powerful and whose influence is amplified by their high-status connections.47
Formal power, as depicted on an organisational chart, and network influence, as revealed by SNA, are two different and often uncorrelated sources of power. The advanced project manager must learn to see and manage both. A critical strategic error can occur when a project manager focuses all their engagement efforts on a stakeholder with a high formal rank but who is isolated within the actual influence network. Conversely, overlooking a lower-ranking employee who happens to have high betweenness centrality - connecting, for instance, the technical team with the user community - can be a catastrophic failure. The person with formal authority may not be the person who can actually unblock an issue or build consensus. A project manager who relies solely on the org chart is operating with a flawed map of reality. The engagement strategy must therefore be two-pronged: one approach for navigating the formal power structure and another, often more critical, for engaging the informal influence network.
This table translates the technical language of SNA into a practical strategic guide, linking each analytical metric directly to a stakeholder management action.

IV.II - Forging Unlikely Alliances by Bridging Structural Holes

One of the most powerful applications of SNA is in the deliberate construction of coalitions. A network map reveals not only who is connected but also who is not. The gaps between distinct clusters of stakeholders are known as "structural holes".43 Stakeholders who can bridge these holes - known as brokers or boundary spanners - are immensely valuable.51 They facilitate the flow of novel information, resources, and perspectives between otherwise isolated groups, which is a critical ingredient for innovation and building broad-based support.53

A project manager can leverage this understanding to move from simply identifying coalitions to actively building them. This process involves a clear, strategic sequence55:

  1. Map the Network: Using survey data, interviews, or observational records, the project manager first identifies the key stakeholders and maps their existing relationships of communication, trust, and collaboration.45
  2. Identify Clusters and Holes: Visual analysis of the network map, often aided by community detection algorithms, will reveal distinct clusters - groups of stakeholders who are densely connected to each other but sparsely connected to other groups.57 These clusters represent existing or potential coalitions. The empty space between these clusters represents the structural holes.
  3. Target the Brokers: The project manager then uses betweenness centrality analysis to pinpoint the specific individuals who are best positioned to bridge these holes. These may be people who are members of multiple groups or who have weak ties into several different communities.53
  4. Facilitate and Incentivise Connection: The final step is to actively engage these identified brokers. The project manager can strategically feed them information, connect them with brokers from other clusters, and create forums (e.g., workshops, joint planning sessions) where they can interact.
By empowering and incentivising these key individuals to connect their respective groups, the project manager can weave together previously separate factions into a new, powerful, and value-creating coalition that can overcome blockers and drive the project forward.56 This transforms the network from a collection of fragmented interests into a cohesive force for project success.
CHAPTER V
Expanding the Pie:
The Blended Value Mandate
The preceding sections have focused on redesigning the strategic interactions between stakeholders. However, even the most collaborative game is limited by the perceived size of the prize. To truly unlock the potential of positive-sum engagement, the advanced project manager must challenge the very definition of project success. The traditional "iron triangle" of scope, time, and cost, while essential for control, provides a narrow and often zero-sum view of value. If the only metric is cost, then any concession to a supplier is a loss. If the only metric is schedule, any delay for quality improvement is a failure. To create a bigger "pie," one must first expand the definition of what the pie is made of.5

V.I - The Blended Value Proposition (BVP)

The conceptual framework for this expansion is the Blended Value Proposition (BVP), a term coined by Jed Emerson. The BVP asserts that value is not a bifurcated concept - either economic or social - but is inherently an integrated and non-divisible blend of economic, social, and environmental components.61 According to this framework, all organisations, whether for-profit or non-profit, create blended value. A for-profit company generates social impact through the jobs it creates and its effect on the community. A non-profit organisation creates economic value through its payroll and its consumption of goods and services.61 The strategic goal, therefore, is not to maximise one type of value at the expense of the others, but to manage for the maximisation of the total, blended value created by an organisation or a project.61

V.II - The Triple Bottom Line (TBL) as a Practical Framework

To make the abstract concept of Blended Value operational for a project manager, the most effective tool is the Triple Bottom Line (TBL) framework. Popularised by John Elkington, the TBL proposes that organisational and project performance should be measured across three interwoven dimensions, often called the "3Ps": People, Planet, and Profit.64

  • Profit (Economic Value): This dimension extends beyond the project's simple return on investment. It encompasses a broader view of economic health and ethical conduct. This includes ensuring fair and timely payment to all suppliers and employees, paying a fair share of taxes, and fostering economic prosperity in the local community by prioritising local sourcing where feasible.67
  • People (Social Value): This dimension measures the project's impact on its human stakeholders. For internal stakeholders, this includes fair wages, safe working conditions, investment in training and professional development, and employee well-being.64 For external stakeholders, it considers the project's impact on the health, well-being, equity, and quality of life of the surrounding community.64
  • Planet (Environmental Value): This dimension quantifies the project's environmental footprint. It involves measuring and managing the consumption of resources like energy and water, the generation of waste, greenhouse gas emissions, and the sustainability of the materials used in the project's lifecycle.64
Adopting a Blended Value framework is the ultimate "game design" strategy. It fundamentally changes the "payoffs" by introducing new, non-financial currencies into the negotiation, which makes it exponentially easier to find win-win, positive-sum outcomes. A standard project negotiation often revolves around a single currency, such as money or time, which is an inherently zero-sum contest. The Blended Value framework, however, introduces multiple, distinct value currencies. Different stakeholders naturally have different preferences and priorities. A community group may value the creation of local jobs (social value) far more than a slight increase in the project's financial cost. An environmentally focused regulator may prioritise reduced emissions (environmental value) over an accelerated timeline. By defining and measuring these different forms of value, the project manager can facilitate trades across these currencies. For instance, a contractor might be convinced to accept a slightly lower profit margin (a loss in economic currency) in exchange for using an innovative, sustainable building method that earns them an industry award and enhances their green reputation (a significant gain in social/reputational currency). This is no longer a zero-sum trade. The project delivers a more sustainable outcome, the contractor gains valuable market differentiation, and the total "pie" of value created has been significantly expanded. Blended Value is therefore not just a reporting framework; it is a powerful strategic tool for creating the conditions necessary for positive-sum negotiation.

V.III - Measuring Blended Value

The primary challenge of implementing a TBL framework is measurement, as social and environmental outcomes can be difficult to quantify in universally accepted terms.64 However, several robust frameworks and tools have emerged to address this68:
  • Key Performance Indicators (KPIs): The first step is to define specific, measurable KPIs for each of the 3Ps. This moves the concept from a philosophical commitment to a manageable set of performance indicators.66
  • Social Return on Investment (SROI): This methodology attempts to monetise social and environmental value by creating financial proxies. For example, the value of a job creation program can be estimated by calculating the public savings on welfare payments and the increased tax revenue generated by the newly employed workers. SROI analysis results in a cost-benefit ratio that reflects the blended value return of an investment.68
  • Standardised Reporting Frameworks: Organisations like the Global Reporting Initiative (GRI) and tools like the Impact Reporting and Investment Standards (IRIS) provide extensive catalogs of standardised metrics for social, environmental, and governance performance. Using these standards allows for consistent tracking and benchmarking.69
V.IV - Case Spotlight: The B Corp Movement

The B Corp movement provides a powerful, real-world example of Blended Value in action.71 Certified B Corps are for-profit companies that have undergone a rigorous assessment of their social and environmental performance, and have made a legal commitment to be accountable to all stakeholders - not just shareholders.74
  • Legal and Governance Change: To certify, a company must amend its governing documents to require the consideration of stakeholder interests (employees, community, environment, customers, suppliers) in its decision-making. This embeds the Blended Value philosophy into the company's legal DNA.71
  • The B Impact Assessment (BIA): This is the tangible measurement tool at the heart of the B Corp certification. It is a comprehensive assessment that scores a company's performance across five key areas: Governance, Workers, Community, Environment, and Customers.75 A company must achieve a minimum verified score of 80 out of 200 to certify, providing a clear benchmark for TBL performance.
  • A Roadmap for Continuous Improvement: Certification is not a one-time event. B Corps must recertify every three years, forcing them to engage in a cycle of continuous improvement and demonstrating long-term resiliency.74 The BIA itself serves as a roadmap, highlighting areas for improvement and providing best practices.76
The B Corp movement demonstrates that the principles of Blended Value and the TBL can be moved from theory to practice. It provides a credible, transparent, and legally robust framework that any project or organisation can look to as a model for how to operationalise a commitment to creating value for all stakeholders, thereby fundamentally enlarging the pie and making positive-sum outcomes the core business of the enterprise.
CHAPTER VI
Case Study in Collaborative Victory:
The Creation of Industry-Wide Technology Standards
The concepts of game theory, coalition building, and positive-sum outcomes can seem theoretical. However, their power is vividly illustrated in one of the most significant collaborative successes in modern business history: the creation of universal technology standards like the Universal Serial Bus (USB) and Bluetooth. The story of their development serves as a capstone case study, demonstrating how a group of fierce competitors can be marshalled to abandon a zero-sum war in favour of a positive-sum victory that creates a vastly larger market for everyone.7

VI.I - The Initial State: A Zero-Sum Mess

Before the advent of universal standards, the world of computer peripherals and wireless connectivity was a fragmented and frustrating landscape. Each manufacturer - Apple, IBM, Compaq, and others - had its own proprietary ports and connectors. This created a classic "lock-in" effect for consumers; buying a printer from one company meant you were more likely to buy your next computer from that same company to ensure compatibility.80 This environment was the epitome of a zero-sum game. The market was balkanised, with each company fighting to make its proprietary ecosystem dominant. This competition stifled innovation, as peripheral manufacturers were unwilling to invest heavily in devices for standards with limited market share, and it created immense inconvenience for consumers.80 The "pie" was small and fiercely contested.

VI.II - Designing a New Game: The Role of the Special Interest Group (SIG) and Implementers Forum (IF)

The breakthrough came not from one company "winning" the standards war, but from a few key players realising that the war itself was the problem. They understood that a universal standard would dramatically expand the entire market for computers and peripherals, and that a smaller slice of a massively larger pie was far more valuable than 100% of a small one. This was a conscious shift from a zero-sum to a positive-sum mindset, driven by enlightened self-interest. To achieve this, they had to architect a new game.

  • The USB Story: In the early 1990s, Intel took the initiative to simplify computer connectivity. Recognising that it could not impose a standard alone, it formed the "USB Promoter Group" in 1994, bringing in rivals like Compaq, IBM, and Microsoft.80 This core group was small enough to be agile but large and representative enough to have industry-wide credibility. To encourage broader adoption, they then established the USB Implementers Forum (USB-IF), a non-profit support organisation that grew to include over 700 companies.80 The USB-IF was tasked with promoting the standard, developing compliance tests, and facilitating the development of a wide range of compatible devices.82
  • The Bluetooth Story: A similar narrative unfolded in wireless technology. In 1998, five major industry players - Ericsson, IBM, Intel, Nokia, and Toshiba - formed the Bluetooth Special Interest Group (SIG).83 The explicit goal was to create an open, short-range wireless specification that all could use. The name itself, taken from the 10th-century king Harald Bluetooth who united Scandinavian tribes, was a metaphor for their mission: to unite disparate devices and technologies.84 The SIG, a not-for-profit trade association, grew to include thousands of member companies and continues to oversee the development and licensing of the Bluetooth standard today.83
VI.III - Applying the Collaborative Arena Framework

The success of these initiatives can be analysed directly through the frameworks developed in this report:

Game Design and Architecture
The formation of the USB-IF and the Bluetooth SIG was a masterful act of game design. These organisations fundamentally changed the game's core elements:

  • They changed the rules: Instead of closed, proprietary systems, they established open specifications that anyone could build upon. They created qualification and compliance programs to ensure interoperability, which became a new rule of the game.88
  • They changed the players: They created a formal, inclusive forum that brought hundreds of companies into the development process, transforming isolated competitors into a collaborative ecosystem.82
  • They changed the payoffs: The most critical move was altering the payoff structure. Through mechanisms like patent pools, where multiple patent holders aggregate their rights and license them collectively, the incentive to litigate was removed.80 The new, highest payoff came not from defending a proprietary technology but from contributing to and benefiting from the growth of the shared standard. Membership in the SIG/IF granted access to intellectual property and the right to use the valuable Bluetooth or USB logo, making cooperation far more lucrative than defection.80
Overcoming the Prisoner's Dilemma
The SIG/IF structure provided the perfect solution to the Prisoner's Dilemma. It created a framework for repeated interaction and trust-building among members. It established a clear "shadow of the future": cooperating by adhering to the standard was rewarded with market access and interoperability, while defecting (e.g., creating an incompatible version) would be punished by exclusion from the ecosystem and loss of the certified logo. The SIG acted as a trusted third party and enforcement mechanism, ensuring that cooperation was the most stable and rational long-term strategy for all players.30

Coalition Building
The SIG and IF are, in essence, highly formalised and successful coalitions. They began with a core group of powerful promoters and strategically expanded to include a diverse network of stakeholders—hardware manufacturers, software developers, and peripheral makers.80 This created a powerful network effect; as more companies joined and produced compatible products, the value of the standard grew for everyone, which in turn attracted even more members. This broad, powerful coalition ensured the standard's widespread adoption and its victory over competing, non-cooperative technologies.

VI.IV - Actionable Lessons for Project Managers

The story of these technology standards holds profound lessons for project managers leading complex initiatives with multiple, often competing, stakeholders. While a project manager may not be creating a global standard, they can act as the convener of their own "mini-SIG" for their project. The key takeaway is that the success of these collaborations was not based on altruism. It was based on a sophisticated understanding of enlightened self-interest. The companies involved realised they could achieve a far greater individual return by collaborating to create a massive, shared platform than they could by winning a smaller, proprietary war.

This provides the project manager with a powerful argument to use when convincing competitive stakeholders to cooperate. The PM's job is to perform the analysis and paint a compelling picture of the vastly larger "pie" that collaborative action can create. The argument is not "let's be nice to each other," but rather, "let's structure our engagement in a way that allows us all to achieve our core objectives more effectively and create more value together than we ever could apart."

A project manager can apply these lessons by:

  1. Identifying a Shared Threat or Opportunity: Just as the "mess" of proprietary cables was a shared problem, the PM can identify a common pain point or a significant mutual opportunity that affects all key stakeholders.
  2. Convening a "Promoter Group": Identify a small group of the most influential and forward-thinking stakeholders to act as the initial champions for a more collaborative approach.
  3. Establishing a "Project Charter as Constitution": Co-create a charter that goes beyond scope and budget to define the rules of engagement, shared goals, a transparent governance structure, and decision-making protocols for the project. This document becomes the constitution for the project's collaborative game.
  4. Creating Shared Payoffs: Work with stakeholders to define success in blended value terms and build in gain-sharing or other collective incentive mechanisms to ensure that when the project wins, everyone wins.
By emulating the strategic collaboration of the tech giants, the project manager can transform a project from a collection of competing interests into a powerful, value-creating coalition.
CONCLUSION
The Positive-Sum Playbook for the Advanced Project Manager
The journey through the collaborative arena reveals a fundamental truth: the highest form of strategic project leadership lies not in mastering the art of conflict, but in mastering the art of collaboration. The traditional view of stakeholder management, rooted in power dynamics and zero-sum competition, is a limited and outdated model for the complex, interconnected projects of the 21st century. The advanced project manager understands that their greatest leverage comes from their ability to architect the strategic environment itself - to design a "game" where cooperation is not an act of altruism, but the most rational path to achieving superior outcomes for all.

This report has synthesised concepts from game theory, social network analysis, and value theory into a coherent strategic model. This model is not a collection of disparate tactics but an integrated playbook for shifting any project environment from a zero-sum battlefield to a positive-sum collaborative arena.

The core principles of this playbook provide a guide for action:

  1. Always Look for the Positive-Sum Game. Make the first strategic move a conscious rejection of the zero-sum assumption. Actively reframe problems from distributive ("who gets what?") to creative ("how can we create more value for everyone?"). Use data and analysis to demonstrate to stakeholders how collaboration expands the pie, appealing to their enlightened self-interest.
  2. Play the Long Game. Recognise that projects are iterated games where reputation is a valuable currency. Employ strategies like Tit-for-Tat not just as a negotiation tactic, but as an algorithm for building and testing trust. Be nice, but retaliatory; be forgiving, but not exploitable. Build a reputation for fairness and predictable reciprocity to foster stable, long-term relationships.
  3. Be the Architect, Not Just the Player. Move beyond reacting to the game and start designing it. Use the project's communication plan and incentive systems as your primary architectural tools. Design them in concert to create a coherent "choice infrastructure" where the rules of engagement and the structure of payoffs make cooperation the path of least resistance.
  4. Map the True Network of Influence. Look beyond the formal organisational chart. Use the principles of Social Network Analysis to identify the hidden hubs, brokers, and influencers who hold the real keys to communication and coalition building. Engage these critical nodes to weave together disparate groups and build powerful, value-creating alliances that can overcome blockers and drive project success.
  5. Enlarge the Pie Before You Slice It. Challenge narrow, traditional definitions of project value. Adopt a Blended Value mindset and use the Triple Bottom Line framework of People, Planet, and Profit to introduce new "currencies" into the negotiation. By measuring and managing social and environmental outcomes alongside financial ones, you create more opportunities for mutually beneficial trade-offs and innovative, win-win solutions.
Embracing this collaborative, value-creating paradigm is not a "soft skill." It is the pinnacle of strategic project leadership. It requires a more sophisticated analytical toolkit, a more demanding level of stakeholder empathy, and a more proactive approach to shaping the project environment. Ultimately, it redefines the project manager's role from a manager of constraints to a creator of value, capable of delivering not just successful projects, but lasting, positive-sum impact for all involved.
References
  1. Game theory in project management, PM Expert, accessed on July 26, 2025
  2. Ultimate Guide to Game Theory: Principles and Applications, accessed on July 26, 2025
  3. Moderated effect of value co-creation on project performance ..., accessed on July 26, 2025
  4. How Value Co-Creation Can Boost Your Innovation Process, accessed on July 26, 2025,
  5. POSITIVE SUM DESIGN: DESIGN METHODS & STRATEGIES ..., accessed on July 26, 2025,
  6. Negative, Zero, and Positive Sum. Capitalism, Character, and Where We Are… | by Mark Fournier | Medium, accessed on July 26, 2025
  7. Zero Sum Game (and Non Zero Sum) - Corporate Finance Institute, accessed on July 26, 2025
  8. Zero-Sum Game Meaning: Examples of Zero-Sum ... - MasterClass, accessed on July 26, 2025
  9. Zero-Sum Game Definition in Finance, With Examples - Investopedia, accessed on July 26, 2025
  10. ELI5 What is a zero-sum game? : r/explainlikeimfive - Reddit, accessed on July 26, 2025
  11. Positive Sum License - Dev4X, accessed on July 26, 2025
  12. Are entrepreneurs generally non-zero-sum or zero-sum people? : r/Entrepreneur - Reddit, accessed on July 26, 2025
  13. The practical uses of Game Theory in Project Management, accessed on July 26, 2025
  14. Messages on Game Theory in Project Management - ProjectManagement.com, accessed on July 26, 2025
  15. Role of Game Theory in Project Management - Rememo, accessed on July 26, 2025
  16. What Is Game Theory? How Game Theory Applies to Business - 2025 - MasterClass, accessed on July 26, 2025
  17. Non-Zero-Sum Games - CS Stanford, accessed on July 26, 2025
  18. The prisoner's dilemma in negotiation: A business perspective - Blogs Institucionals UOC, accessed on July 26, 2025
  19. Game Theory in Project Management: A Strategic Playbook for Success - JIITAK, accessed on July 26, 2025
  20. What Is the Prisoner's Dilemma and How Does It Work? - Investopedia, accessed on July 26, 2025
  21. The Prisoner's Dilemma: Real Life Application of Game Theory - ResearchGate, accessed on July 26, 2025
  22. The Prisoner's Dilemma - definition, meaning and examples - Glossary - Lectera, accessed on July 26, 2025
  23. New Game Theory Shows Better Path to Cooperation - ProMarket, accessed on July 26, 2025
  24. Tit for tat - Wikipedia, accessed on July 26, 2025
  25. What Does Tit for Tat Mean, and How Does It Work? - Investopedia, accessed on July 26, 2025
  26. The Morality and Practicality of Tit for Tat – The Philosophy, Politics, and Economics Review, accessed on July 26, 2025
  27. Strategies for promoting cooperation (e.g., tit-for-tat) | Game Theory Class Notes - Fiveable, accessed on July 26, 2025
  28. Tit For Tat - Farnam Street, accessed on July 26, 2025,
  29. Architects the prisoners of dilemma | by Michael Lewarne | Bootcamp - Medium, accessed on July 26, 2025
  30. Navigating the Prisoners' Dilemma in Global Governance - Number Analytics, accessed on July 26, 2025
  31. An Introduction to Positive Sum Design - Digital Commons @ RISD, accessed on July 26, 2025
  32. How to Create a Communication Plan [+ a Template] | The Workstream - Atlassian, accessed on July 26, 2025
  33. Effective communication protocols for remote teams: Why they matter, and how to create them, accessed on July 26, 2025
  34. Team Communication Protocol: Definition, Examples, and Applications | LaunchNotes, accessed on July 26, 2025
  35. Effective Communication Strategies For Project Teams - Gururo, accessed on July 26, 2025,
  36. Designing Effective Incentive Systems - FasterCapital, accessed on July 26, 2025
  37. The Five Pillars of Incentive Design | Guerdon Associates, accessed on July 26, 2025
  38. INCENTIVE SYSTEMS TO SUPPORT COLLABORATION IN CONSTRUCTION PROJECTS - KIT - TMB, accessed on July 26, 2025
  39. #1 Employee Incentive System Strategies [2025 Guide] - Matter, accessed on July 26, 2025
  40. Designing incentive systems for participation in digital ecosystems—An integrated framework - ResearchGate, accessed on July 26, 2025
  41. Unlocking Strategic Decisions: A Deep Dive into Cooperative and Competitive Game Theory | by Sam Affolter | Medium, accessed on July 26, 2025
  42. Leveraging Sustainable Business Cooperation and Game Theory for Competitive Advantage in Dominated Markets, accessed on July 26, 2025
  43. (PDF) The Role of Social Networks Theory and Methodology for ..., accessed on July 26, 2025
  44. What is Stakeholder Mapping? Techniques and Steps - SixSigma.us, accessed on July 26, 2025
  45. Using Social Network Analysis to Evaluate Connections among Stakeholders, accessed on July 26, 2025
  46. Modeling Project Stakeholder Influence Using Social Network ..., accessed on July 26, 2025
  47. Centrality and Community in Project Stakeholder Networks - Robin Nicklas, accessed on July 26, 2025
  48. Network Centrality: Understanding Degree, Closeness & Betweenness Centrality, accessed on July 26, 2025
  49. Centrality Measures In Social Network Analysis - FasterCapital, accessed on July 26, 2025
  50. Exploring the Impact of Eigenvector Centrality in Social Networks - Number Analytics, accessed on July 26, 2025
  51. Mapping your stakeholder network, accessed on July 26, 2025
  52. (PDF) Bridges, brokers and boundary spanners in collaborative networks: A systematic review - ResearchGate, accessed on July 26, 2025
  53. AEC535/WC197: Introduction to Social Network Research: Brokerage Typology?, accessed on July 26, 2025
  54. Understanding Brokers, Intermediaries, and Boundary Spanners - OSF, accessed on July 26, 2025
  55. How to Build Networked Coalitions - The Commons, accessed on July 26, 2025
  56. Policy Networks in Action - Number Analytics, accessed on July 26, 2025
  57. Combining Stakeholder- and Social Network- Analysis to Improve Regional Nature Conservation: A Case Study from Osnabrück, Germany - PubMed Central, accessed on July 26, 2025
  58. Comprehensive Guide on Stakeholder Network Mapping - TSC.ai, accessed on July 26, 2025
  59. How to Use Social Network Analysis to Strengthen Cross-Sector Partnerships, accessed on July 26, 2025
  60. Coalition Building and Stakeholder Engagement | Public Health Social Sciences Class Notes | Fiveable, accessed on July 26, 2025
  61. Framework — Blended Value, accessed on July 26, 2025
  62. Unlocking Blended Value in Nonprofits - Number Analytics, accessed on July 26, 2025
  63. The Blended Value Proposition: Integrating Social and Financial Returns - ResearchGate, accessed on July 26, 2025
  64. The Triple Bottom Line: What Is It and How Does It Work?, accessed on July 26, 2025
  65. Project management and sustainability - The sustainability components, accessed on July 26, 2025
  66. Implementing Triple Bottom Line Framework for Sustainable Agile Success, accessed on July 26, 2025
  67. Triple Bottom Line: What It Is and How to Measure - Investopedia, accessed on July 26, 2025
  68. Blended Value: The Future of Nonprofit Success - Number Analytics, accessed on July 26, 2025
  69. Measuring Blended Value - Shelterforce, accessed on July 26, 2025
  70. The Blended Value Proposition - FasterCapital, accessed on July 26, 2025
  71. B Corporation (certification) - Wikipedia, accessed on July 26, 2025
  72. B Corp certification: The development of a key sustainability standard - Nexio Projects, accessed on July 26, 2025
  73. B Corp Certification demonstrates a company's entire social and ..., accessed on July 26, 2025
  74. B Corp Certification demonstrates a company's entire social and environmental impact., accessed on July 26, 2025
  75. What Is B Corp? Certification Guide and Quick Assessment - Green Business Benchmark°, accessed on July 26, 2025,
  76. What does the B Corp certification mean? - B Lab Europe, accessed on July 26, 2025
  77. B Corp Certification - Heather Paulsen Consulting, accessed on July 26, 2025
  78. Digital B Corp Program - Move to Impact, accessed on July 26, 2025
  79. Positive Sum - Sustainable Business Transformation, accessed on July 26, 2025
  80. THE DEVELOPMENT OF THE USB STANDARD | Frontier Economics, accessed on July 26, 2025
  81. Top IT firms form group to boost next-gen USB - CRN, accessed on July 26, 2025
  82. About USB-IF, accessed on July 26, 2025
  83. (PDF) 25 Years of Bluetooth Technology - ResearchGate, accessed on July 26, 2025
  84. The History of Bluetooth: A Comprehensive Development - Minew, accessed on July 26, 2025
  85. Evolution of Bluetooth Technology: BLE in the IoT Ecosystem - PMC - PubMed Central, accessed on July 26, 2025
  86. Bluetooth Special Interest Group - Wikipedia, accessed on July 26, 2025
  87. Bluetooth Special Interest Group (SIG) Case Study - Auth0, accessed on July 26, 2025
  88. Certification Requirements for Bluetooth SIG, accessed on July 26, 2025
  89. Bluetooth® SIG Certification and Logo Qualification - IB-Lenhardt, accessed on July 26, 2025
Made on
Tilda